I research technology, innovation, investment allocation, and the role of money, trade, and other resources in political competition. I received my PhD from Princeton University in 2020.
Dissertation:
The Political Causes and Consequences of Technological Change. Department of Politics, Princeton University, 2020. Advisers: Helen V. Milner (chair), Carles Boix, Matias Iaryczower.
This dissertation explores the political causes and consequences of technological change. In three essays, I show that new technology and trade shape states’ economies, politics, and relations with each other.
Click here for a 5-Page introduction (PDF)
Peer-reviewed:
Milner, H.V. and Solstad, S.U., 2021. Technological Change and the International System. World Politics, 73(3), pp. 545-589.
Presented at University of Oxford (2020), Rutgers University (2019), the Princeton International Relations Faculty Colloquium (2018), and the Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy Society (“IPES” 2018). PDF.
Abstract: Do world politics affect the adoption of new technology? States overwhelmingly rely on technology invented abroad, and their differential intensity of technology use accounts for many of their differences in economic development. Much of the literature on technology adoption focuses on domestic conditions. The authors argue instead that the structure of the international system is critical because it affects the level of competition among states, which in turn affects leaders’ willingness to enact policies that speed technology adoption. Countries adopt new technology as they seek to avoid being vulnerable to attack or coercion by other countries. By systematically examining states’ adoption of technology over the past two hundred years, the authors find that countries adopt new technologies faster when the international system is less concentrated, that changes in systemic concentration have a temporally causal effect on technology adoption, and that government policies to promote technology adoption are related to concerns about rising international competition. A competitive international system is an important incentive for technological change and may underlie global technology waves.
Under review:
Political Competition in Dynamic Economies. Presented at the University of Oxford Political Economy of Finance Conference (2018), the Atlanta Conference on Science and Innovation Policy (2017), in the Princeton University Political Economy Colloquium (2017, 2019), and the Princeton University International Relations Colloquium (2016). Currently under revisions for resubmission.
Abstract: How does economic opportunity – the set of possible investments in an economy – shape politics, and politics shape investment? I argue that in a world where money is power, political leaders will intervene in the economy if investment returns shift power and threaten their position. Anticipation of such action induces a bias towards investments which vary less and co-vary with the investments of the regime. Leaders will then weigh losses from such intervention and biased allocation, which depends on possible investments (their risk and covariance), with the costs of a larger and less vulnerable coalition. I provide casual evidence of this process using a revolution in transport technology – the steamship – which radically altered economic opportunity in the 19th century. I show that not only do large coalition regimes such as democracies have an inherent investment edge in high-risk projects, such as new technology and international trade, but that they are more likely to emerge if that is where economic opportunities are.
Does Globalization Bring Peace? A Study of Trade and Interstate War, 1845-1905. Presented in the Princeton University Political Economy Colloquium (2018), at the Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meeting (2018) and the Princeton University International Relations Colloquium (2017). Under review.
Abstract: Testing the link between trade and peace, both between and within countries, has so far been difficult due to the lack of a good instrument for trade. I leverage a novel instrument for trade – the change in effective shipping distances due to the invention and adoption of steam technology (Pascali 2017) – to study the relationship between increases in trade and countries’ propensity for conflict. I find that as countries trade more overall, the probability that they go to war goes down, in a relationship not driven by bilateral effects, and not present for civil war. This has implications both for our understanding of the first wave of globalization, and the one we are experiencing today: I provide evidence in favor of a “commercial peace” that is general, and not within or between particular states.

Working papers:
Trade, Technology, and Growth
Can progress arrive by container? I estimate the global adoption of shipping containers in oceanic trade, container and non-container shipping routes, and use the three to construct a novel instrument for trade in the post-1960 era. I use this instrument to assess if trade brought economic growth, and if so, the extent to which this growth can be attributed to increased technology use, technology innovation, economic specialization, democracy or peaceful international relations — and how trade can be related to these as outcomes in their own right. In so doing, I use and make accessible new data on technology innovation, port-to-port oceanic distances, and a novel measure of how economies change based on product-level trade composition. I find that trade brought growth, in part through increased technology use and innovation, changed economies, and peaceful economic relations.

Smart Social Networks: How AI-Curation Polarizes and Empowers Extremism in Online Communities
What are the consequences of AI curation for online communities? I build a simulation of a social media platform in which users have dynamic views, generate and share content based on these views, and an AI algorithm connects users with similar content. I find: (1) AI curation leads to view polarization, (2) these effects are magnified the more accurate the AI algorithm is, and (3) that more accurate AI-groupings make users who have views that are extreme and unchanging (trolls/extremists) have a higher impact. I assess the robustness of these findings using a range of AI grouping strategies, number of groups, users, starting views, and content generation procedures.

High Seas, High Stakes: The Importance of Open Waters
Abstract: More than 90 percent of international trade is carried by sea. How vulnerable is this trade – and the economic interdependence it enables – to disruption? Research on the vulnerability of international trade has been done at the country, region, or case basis. But disruption of international trade by war, terrorism, piracy or natural catastrophe tend to be in specific geographical – not political – areas. I estimate the economic value of unimpeded travel of all the world’s ocean areas at the 3 longitude times 3 latitude level. I here calculate how much disruption in each area – the area being closed to commerce – increases transportation costs, by calculating all optimal alternative ship routes. I also estimate the vulnerabilities of the United States, Japan and China in particular. I thus aim to contribute to the literature by: (1) identifying the world’s key arenas of contention from the perspective of controlling international commerce, (2) providing measures of the economic impact of a shutdown of specific ocean areas and choke-points, and (3) establishing a baseline estimate of several countries’ trade-flow vulnerabilities.

Team of Experts: a Novel and Fast Approach to Machine Learning Extremization
I utilize theory from Satopaa et al (2015) to construct a new ensemble machine learning algorithm based on dynamic extremization. Offers very rapid convergence, estimates of information accessed, and near-unlimited parallellization.
The Soil of Politics: Resources, Competition, and the Consequences of Ethnic Inequality, with Rachael McLellan. Presented at the 4th Annual Conference of the History and Politics Network (2017), the Princeton Political Economy Colloquium (2017), and APSA (2016). PDF. Under review.
Abstract: Resources matter in political competition, and control of fertile land especially so. In many countries, ethnic groups are the building blocks of political coalitions. We combine these two insights, and argue that an ethnic groups’ control of fertile land — which we call “soil power” — shape their bargaining power in national politics. This in turn shapes national political outcomes. We use satellite and soil data to calculate the cumulative agricultural potential of ethnic homelands in several common datasets. We demonstrate that soil power predicts a groups’ national power and its risk of discrimination, beyond that which can be explained by population share. Using maps of ethnic group homelands as they were in the 1880s and theory from the literature on ethno-linguistic fractionalization, we also evidence and formalize a new deleterious legacy of colonialism: the creation of countries in which the distribution of land resources made governance extremely hard.

Software:
seeAI – Visualizations of Machines Learning in R. Available on my Github.
The seeAI package aims to visualize common machine learning procedures. Visuals are dynamically generated based on supplied models so as to be useful for both teachers/students and practitioners. It currently supports the popular glmnet implementation of cross-validated lasso regression.
Coverage – an R package for seeing what you are missing. Available on my Github.
The coverage package and associated function provides you with a summary of your time and unit coverage, producing compact tables and a visual representation. This is important for any analysis conducted with row-wise deletion in the presence of missing data, especially if one suspect that patterns of missingness are non-random with respect to variables of interest. Analysis which use row-wise deletion include standard regression analysis and most implementations of maximum likelihood. See my Github for examples and details.
The “out-of-the-box” visual output below shows country and year coverage for a technology-country-year analysis, with darker blue indicating more observations, and grey indicating years in which the unit in question did not exist as an independent country:
QuickReg – Easy OLS with options in R. Available on my Github.
The QuickReg package and associated function provides an easy interface for linear regression in R. This includes the option to request robust and clustered standard errors, automatic labeling, an easy way to specify multiple regression specifications simultaneously, and a compact html or latex output (relying on the widely used “stargazer” package).
QuickReg also includes several functionalities to speed up OLS computation, including a special implementation of the method of alternating projections. This method reduces calculation time drastically (>60 percent in tests) for analysis with a large number of fixed effects, with a performance gain that is increasing in the number of regression specifications passed to the function simultaneously.
QuickCoefPlot – Easy OLS coefficient plots with options in R. Available on my Github.
The QuickCoefPlot package turns base R’s linear-model objects into easy-to-read coefficient plots, complete with model statistics, labeling and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors (by default). Includes a range of options, including the opportunity to request default or clustered standard errors, the option to calculate and report bootstrapped confidence intervals and/or estimates, and change text-size, plot title, which model statistics or coefficients to report, and so on.
# Use the QuickCoefPlot to produce a coefficient plot model <- lm(log_gdppc_mad ~ polity2 + tropical + desert + soil + near_coast + year, data = mydata) qcp(model)
QuickEffectSize – Easy effect size plots with options in R. Available on my Github.
QuickEffectSize is an easy interface for effect size plots in R. Using the Zelig package and ggplot2, it simulates and visualizes effect sizes of any zelig model: simply supply the model and the variable.
# Produce an effect size plot using QuickEffectSize dat <- data.frame(y = rnorm(100), x1 = rnorm(100), x2 = rnorm(100)) dat$x3 <- dat$y + rnorm(100) example.model <- zelig(y ~ x1 + x2 + x3, data = dat, model = "normal", cite = FALSE) qes(example.model, iv.var = "x3", xlab = "Using qes", ylab = "Productivity", progress = FALSE)
Data:
The US Patent Data Set (1976-2015)
Data Set of all patents granted in the United States between 1976 and 2015, with information on patent class, country and city of inventor, and number of times cited by other patents. Includes 5.9 million patents and 31.6 million associated citations.

The Military Technology Data Set
- Country-year adoption rate of 33 military technologies. 105 425 data points at the country-technology-year level.